Difference between revisions of "Boldrin and Levine (2005)"

From Copyright EVIDENCE
Line 2: Line 2:
 
|Source={{Source
 
|Source={{Source
 
|Name of Study=Boldrin and Levine (2005)
 
|Name of Study=Boldrin and Levine (2005)
|Author=Boldrin, M; Levine, DK
+
|Author=Boldrin, M.; Levine, D.K.;
 
|Title=Intellectual property and the efficient allocation of social surplus from creation
 
|Title=Intellectual property and the efficient allocation of social surplus from creation
 
|Year=2005
 
|Year=2005
Line 9: Line 9:
 
|Authentic Link=http://www.serci.org/rerci.html#Vol2No1
 
|Authentic Link=http://www.serci.org/rerci.html#Vol2No1
 
|Link=http://ssrn.com/abstract=1144885
 
|Link=http://ssrn.com/abstract=1144885
|Reference=Nordhaus (1969); Romer (1986); Boldrin and Levine (1999); Liebowitz (1985); Legros (2005);
+
|Reference=Nordhaus (1969);Romer (1986);Boldrin and Levine (1999);Liebowitz (1985);Legros (2005);
|Plain Text Proposition=* An almost complete abolition of IP protection would lead to more creative activity, a more efficient allocation of its surplus, and higher social welfare.
+
|Plain Text Proposition=* An almost complete abolition of IP protection would lead to more creative activity, a more efficient allocation of its surplus, and higher social welfare.* In the standard model of innovation, no innovation takes place under NIP (non IP). While these may not be, and are not in our view, the empirically relevant circumstances, they are those almost invariably adopted to argue for the necessity of strong IP legislation.* There are abundant doubts on the established wisdom, according to which more IP protection is, from a social viewpoint, always better than less.* The presence of IP protection may eventually lead to an ever decreasing amount of creation.* A NIP systems allows the best creative individuals to earn large amounts of money.* In the IP system, income inequality gets larger  without gains for social welfare.* The starting point of the economic analysis of innovation is to recognize that the economically relevant unit is a copy of an idea.  Economically valuable copies of ideas do not fall from the heavens, like manna, but are the product of intentional and costly human efforts.
 
+
|FundamentalIssue=1. Relationship between protection (subject matter/term/scope) and supply/economic development/growth/welfare,2. Relationship between creative process and protection - what motivates creators (e.g. attribution; control; remuneration; time allocation)?,5. Understanding consumption/use (e.g. determinants of unlawful behaviour; user-generated content; social media)
* In the standard model of innovation, no innovation takes place under NIP (non IP). While these may not be, and are not in our view, the empirically relevant circumstances, they are those almost invariably adopted to argue for the necessity of strong IP legislation.
+
|EvidenceBasedPolicy=F. Enforcement (quantifying infringement; criminal sanctions; intermediary liability; graduated response; litigation and court data; commercial/non-commercial distinction; education and awareness),E. Fair remuneration (levies; copyright contracts),A. Nature and Scope of exclusive rights (hyperlinking/browsing; reproduction right)
 
 
* There are abundant doubts on the established wisdom, according to which more IP protection is, from a social viewpoint, always better than less.
 
 
 
* The presence of IP protection may eventually lead to an ever decreasing amount of creation.
 
 
 
* A NIP systems allows the best creative individuals to earn large amounts of money.
 
 
 
* In the IP system, income inequality gets larger  without gains for social welfare.
 
 
 
* The starting point of the economic analysis of innovation is to recognize that the economically relevant unit is a copy of an idea.  Economically valuable copies of ideas do not fall from the heavens, like manna, but are the product of intentional and costly human efforts.
 
|FundamentalIssue=1. Relationship between protection (subject matter/term/scope) and supply/economic development/growth/welfare, 2. Relationship between creative process and protection - what motivates creators (e.g. attribution; control; remuneration; time allocation)?, 5. Understanding consumption/use (e.g. determinants of unlawful behaviour; user-generated content; social media),
 
|EvidenceBasedPolicy=F. Enforcement (quantifying infringement; criminal sanctions; intermediary liability; graduated response; litigation and court data; commercial/non-commercial distinction; education and awareness), E. Fair remuneration (levies; copyright contracts), A. Nature and Scope of exclusive rights (hyperlinking/browsing; reproduction right),
 
 
|Discipline=A12: Relation of Economics to Other Disciplines, A13: Relation of Economics to Social Values, K1: Basic Areas of Law, O34: Intellectual Property and Intellectual Capital
 
|Discipline=A12: Relation of Economics to Other Disciplines, A13: Relation of Economics to Social Values, K1: Basic Areas of Law, O34: Intellectual Property and Intellectual Capital
|Intervention-Response=* Even if this should not be the concern of a policy aimed at maximizing social welfare, a NIP system would not necessarily impoverish creative individuals, but instead it would allow the best among them to still earn large amounts of money
+
|Intervention-Response=* Even if this should not be the concern of a policy aimed at maximizing social welfare, a NIP system would not necessarily impoverish creative individuals, but instead it would allow the best among them to still earn large amounts of money* A great deal of common economic wisdom applies equally well to the economics of knowledge* Property rights in copies of ideas is assured by the ordinary laws against theft – what is ordinarily referred to as “intellectual property” protects not the ownership of copies of ideas, but rather a monopoly over how other people make use of their copies of an idea.
 
 
* A great deal of common economic wisdom applies equally well to the economics of knowledge
 
 
 
* Property rights in copies of ideas is assured by the ordinary laws against theft – what is ordinarily referred to as “intellectual property” protects not the ownership of copies of ideas, but rather a monopoly over how other people make use of their copies of an idea.
 
 
|Description of Data=The authors assess the NIP (non IP) system and characterize its properties.
 
|Description of Data=The authors assess the NIP (non IP) system and characterize its properties.
|Data Year=None stated
 
 
|Data Type=Primary and Secondary data
 
|Data Type=Primary and Secondary data
 
|Data Source=Literature review;
 
|Data Source=Literature review;
Line 44: Line 27:
 
|Dataset={{Dataset
 
|Dataset={{Dataset
 
|Sample Size=1
 
|Sample Size=1
|Level of Aggregation=Economic model,
+
|Level of Aggregation=Economic model
 
|Data Material Year=Non stated
 
|Data Material Year=Non stated
 
}}
 
}}
 
}}
 
}}

Revision as of 14:37, 20 April 2020

Advertising Architectural Publishing of books, periodicals and other publishing Programming and broadcasting Computer programming Computer consultancy Creative, arts and entertainment Cultural education Libraries, archives, museums and other cultural activities

Film and motion pictures Sound recording and music publishing Photographic activities PR and communication Software publishing Video game publishing Specialised design Television programmes Translation and interpretation

1. Relationship between protection (subject matter/term/scope) and supply/economic development/growth/welfare 2. Relationship between creative process and protection - what motivates creators (e.g. attribution; control; remuneration; time allocation)? 3. Harmony of interest assumption between authors and publishers (creators and producers/investors) 4. Effects of protection on industry structure (e.g. oligopolies; competition; economics of superstars; business models; technology adoption) 5. Understanding consumption/use (e.g. determinants of unlawful behaviour; user-generated content; social media)

A. Nature and Scope of exclusive rights (hyperlinking/browsing; reproduction right) B. Exceptions (distinguish innovation and public policy purposes; open-ended/closed list; commercial/non-commercial distinction) C. Mass digitisation/orphan works (non-use; extended collective licensing) D. Licensing and Business models (collecting societies; meta data; exchanges/hubs; windowing; crossborder availability) E. Fair remuneration (levies; copyright contracts) F. Enforcement (quantifying infringement; criminal sanctions; intermediary liability; graduated response; litigation and court data; commercial/non-commercial distinction; education and awareness)

Source Details

Boldrin and Levine (2005)
Title: Intellectual property and the efficient allocation of social surplus from creation
Author(s): Boldrin, M., Levine, D.K.
Year: 2005
Citation: Boldrin, M., & Levine, D. K. (2005). Intellectual property and the efficient allocation of social surplus from creation. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 2(1), 45-67.
Link(s): Definitive , Open Access
Key Related Studies:
Discipline:
Linked by: Raustiala and Sprigman (2019)
About the Data
Data Description: The authors assess the NIP (non IP) system and characterize its properties.
Data Type: Primary and Secondary data
Secondary Data Sources:
Data Collection Methods:
Data Analysis Methods:
Industry(ies):
Country(ies):
Cross Country Study?: No
Comparative Study?: No
Literature review?: No
Government or policy study?: No
Time Period(s) of Collection:
Funder(s):
  • NSF

Abstract

In the modern theory of innovation, monopoly plays a crucial role both as a cause and an effect of creative economic activity. Innovative firms, it is argued, would have insufficient incentive to innovate should the prospect of monopoly power not be present. This theme of monopoly runs throughout the theory of growth, international trade, and industrial organization. We argue that monopoly is neither needed for, nor a necessary consequence of innovation. In particular, intellectual property is not necessary for, and may hurt more than help, innovation and growth. We show that, in most circumstances, competitive rents allow creative individuals to appropriate a large enough share of the social surplus generated by their innovations to compensate for their opportunity cost. We also show that, as the number of pre-existing and IP protected ideas needed for an innovation increases, the equilibrium outcome under the IP regime is one of decreasing probability of innovation, while this is not the case without IP. Finally, we provide various examples of how competitive markets for innovative products would work in the absence of IP and critically discuss a number of common fallacies in the previous literature.

Main Results of the Study

  • An almost complete abolition of IP protection would lead to more creative activity, a more efficient allocation of its surplus, and higher social welfare.* In the standard model of innovation, no innovation takes place under NIP (non IP). While these may not be, and are not in our view, the empirically relevant circumstances, they are those almost invariably adopted to argue for the necessity of strong IP legislation.* There are abundant doubts on the established wisdom, according to which more IP protection is, from a social viewpoint, always better than less.* The presence of IP protection may eventually lead to an ever decreasing amount of creation.* A NIP systems allows the best creative individuals to earn large amounts of money.* In the IP system, income inequality gets larger without gains for social welfare.* The starting point of the economic analysis of innovation is to recognize that the economically relevant unit is a copy of an idea. Economically valuable copies of ideas do not fall from the heavens, like manna, but are the product of intentional and costly human efforts.


Policy Implications as Stated By Author

  • Even if this should not be the concern of a policy aimed at maximizing social welfare, a NIP system would not necessarily impoverish creative individuals, but instead it would allow the best among them to still earn large amounts of money* A great deal of common economic wisdom applies equally well to the economics of knowledge* Property rights in copies of ideas is assured by the ordinary laws against theft – what is ordinarily referred to as “intellectual property” protects not the ownership of copies of ideas, but rather a monopoly over how other people make use of their copies of an idea.


Coverage of Study

Coverage of Fundamental Issues
Issue Included within Study
Relationship between protection (subject matter/term/scope) and supply/economic development/growth/welfare
Green-tick.png
Relationship between creative process and protection - what motivates creators (e.g. attribution; control; remuneration; time allocation)?
Green-tick.png
Harmony of interest assumption between authors and publishers (creators and producers/investors)
Effects of protection on industry structure (e.g. oligopolies; competition; economics of superstars; business models; technology adoption)
Understanding consumption/use (e.g. determinants of unlawful behaviour; user-generated content; social media)
Green-tick.png
Coverage of Evidence Based Policies
Issue Included within Study
Nature and Scope of exclusive rights (hyperlinking/browsing; reproduction right)
Green-tick.png
Exceptions (distinguish innovation and public policy purposes; open-ended/closed list; commercial/non-commercial distinction)
Mass digitisation/orphan works (non-use; extended collective licensing)
Licensing and Business models (collecting societies; meta data; exchanges/hubs; windowing; crossborder availability)
Fair remuneration (levies; copyright contracts)
Green-tick.png
Enforcement (quantifying infringement; criminal sanctions; intermediary liability; graduated response; litigation and court data; commercial/non-commercial distinction; education and awareness)
Green-tick.png

Datasets

Sample size: 1
Level of aggregation: Economic model
Period of material under study: Non stated