Difference between revisions of "Shavell and van Ypersele (1999)"

From Copyright EVIDENCE
m (Saved using "Save and continue" button in form)
Line 10: Line 10:
 
|Authentic Link=http://www.nber.org/papers/w6956.pdf
 
|Authentic Link=http://www.nber.org/papers/w6956.pdf
 
|Link=http://www.nber.org/papers/w6956.pdf
 
|Link=http://www.nber.org/papers/w6956.pdf
|Reference=Boyle (2003); Lemley (2004); Gallini and Scotchmer (2002); Netanel (2003);
+
|Reference=Gallini and Scotchmer (2002); Boyle (2003); Netanel (2003); Lemley (2004);
 
|Plain Text Proposition=In a regime with rewards, drugs would be far cheaper and more widely used, all computer software would be free, and electronically recorded materials would be inexpensive, arguably engendering significant increases in consumer welfare. Moreover, there would also be potential gains from enhanced incentives to innovate, as profits from patent and copyright may fall considerably short of consumer surplus. For example, Kremer suggests that studies of the social versus the private returns from research indicate that private profits from research might well be only one-third of the social returns. Because optimal rewards would reflect the
 
|Plain Text Proposition=In a regime with rewards, drugs would be far cheaper and more widely used, all computer software would be free, and electronically recorded materials would be inexpensive, arguably engendering significant increases in consumer welfare. Moreover, there would also be potential gains from enhanced incentives to innovate, as profits from patent and copyright may fall considerably short of consumer surplus. For example, Kremer suggests that studies of the social versus the private returns from research indicate that private profits from research might well be only one-third of the social returns. Because optimal rewards would reflect the
 
social returns, rewards would increase overall incentives to invest.
 
social returns, rewards would increase overall incentives to invest.
Line 24: Line 24:
 
|Government or policy=No
 
|Government or policy=No
 
|Literature review=Yes
 
|Literature review=Yes
|Funded By=Shavell acknowledges research support from the John M. Olin Center for Law, Economics, and Business at Harvard Law School;
+
|Funded By=John M. Olin Center for Law, Economics, Business at Harvard Law School;
 
}}
 
}}
 
|Dataset=
 
|Dataset=
 
}}
 
}}

Revision as of 06:13, 8 October 2016

Advertising Architectural Publishing of books, periodicals and other publishing Programming and broadcasting Computer programming Computer consultancy Creative, arts and entertainment Cultural education Libraries, archives, museums and other cultural activities

Film and motion pictures Sound recording and music publishing Photographic activities PR and communication Software publishing Video game publishing Specialised design Television programmes Translation and interpretation

1. Relationship between protection (subject matter/term/scope) and supply/economic development/growth/welfare 2. Relationship between creative process and protection - what motivates creators (e.g. attribution; control; remuneration; time allocation)? 3. Harmony of interest assumption between authors and publishers (creators and producers/investors) 4. Effects of protection on industry structure (e.g. oligopolies; competition; economics of superstars; business models; technology adoption) 5. Understanding consumption/use (e.g. determinants of unlawful behaviour; user-generated content; social media)

A. Nature and Scope of exclusive rights (hyperlinking/browsing; reproduction right) B. Exceptions (distinguish innovation and public policy purposes; open-ended/closed list; commercial/non-commercial distinction) C. Mass digitisation/orphan works (non-use; extended collective licensing) D. Licensing and Business models (collecting societies; meta data; exchanges/hubs; windowing; crossborder availability) E. Fair remuneration (levies; copyright contracts) F. Enforcement (quantifying infringement; criminal sanctions; intermediary liability; graduated response; litigation and court data; commercial/non-commercial distinction; education and awareness)

Source Details

Shavell and van Ypersele (1999)
Title: Rewards versus Intellectual Property Rights
Author(s): Steven Shavell, Tanguy van Ypersele
Year: 1999
Citation: Shavell, S. and Van Ypersele, T., 1999. Rewards versus intellectual property rights (No. w6956). National bureau of economic research.
Link(s): Definitive , Open Access
Key Related Studies:
Discipline:
Linked by:
About the Data
Data Description: This study proposes an economic model comparing a reward system with Intellectual Property Rights. It uses no original data.
Data Type:
Secondary Data Sources:
Data Collection Methods:
Data Analysis Methods:
Industry(ies):
Country(ies):
Cross Country Study?: Yes
Comparative Study?: No
Literature review?: Yes
Government or policy study?: No
Time Period(s) of Collection:
Funder(s):
  • John M. Olin Center for Law, Economics, Business at Harvard Law School

Abstract

This paper compares reward systems to intellectual property rights (patents and copyrights). Under a reward system, innovators are paid for innovations directly by the government (possibly on the basis of sales), and innovations pass immediately into the public domain. Thus, reward systems engender incentives to innovate without creating the monopoly power of intellectual property rights. But a principal difficulty with rewards is the information required for their determination. We conclude in our model that intellectual property rights do not possess a fundamental social advantage over reward systems and that an optional reward system—under which innovators choose between rewards and intellectual property rights—is superior to intellectual property rights.

Main Results of the Study

In a regime with rewards, drugs would be far cheaper and more widely used, all computer software would be free, and electronically recorded materials would be inexpensive, arguably engendering significant increases in consumer welfare. Moreover, there would also be potential gains from enhanced incentives to innovate, as profits from patent and copyright may fall considerably short of consumer surplus. For example, Kremer suggests that studies of the social versus the private returns from research indicate that private profits from research might well be only one-third of the social returns. Because optimal rewards would reflect the social returns, rewards would increase overall incentives to invest.

Policy Implications as Stated By Author

Reward systems, or optional reward systems, and especially those based on sales-related information, appear on reflection to hold promise as alternatives to our system of intellectual property rights, because there is no necessity to marry the incentive to innovate to conferral of monopoly power in innovations. As such, serious study of the possibility of reward systems, with a view toward their implementation at least on an experimental, partial basis, is worth contemplating.

Coverage of Study

Coverage of Fundamental Issues
Issue Included within Study
Relationship between protection (subject matter/term/scope) and supply/economic development/growth/welfare
Green-tick.png
Relationship between creative process and protection - what motivates creators (e.g. attribution; control; remuneration; time allocation)?
Green-tick.png
Harmony of interest assumption between authors and publishers (creators and producers/investors)
Effects of protection on industry structure (e.g. oligopolies; competition; economics of superstars; business models; technology adoption)
Green-tick.png
Understanding consumption/use (e.g. determinants of unlawful behaviour; user-generated content; social media)
Coverage of Evidence Based Policies
Issue Included within Study
Nature and Scope of exclusive rights (hyperlinking/browsing; reproduction right)
Green-tick.png
Exceptions (distinguish innovation and public policy purposes; open-ended/closed list; commercial/non-commercial distinction)
Mass digitisation/orphan works (non-use; extended collective licensing)
Licensing and Business models (collecting societies; meta data; exchanges/hubs; windowing; crossborder availability)
Green-tick.png
Fair remuneration (levies; copyright contracts)
Green-tick.png
Enforcement (quantifying infringement; criminal sanctions; intermediary liability; graduated response; litigation and court data; commercial/non-commercial distinction; education and awareness)

Datasets